The Fixed-Price Incentive Firm Target Contract: Not As Firm As the Name Suggests
The Fixed-Price Incentive Firm Target Contract: Not As Firm As the Name Suggests
|
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
At the end of 1976, I met the Director of the Procurement Control and Clearance Division of the Naval Material Command in Arlington, Virginia. The Director was a legend of the contracting community and any significant Navy contract had to be approved by his office prior to award. I was there because of a controversy involving a contract to acquire a new class of nuclear cruisers. The attendees at the meeting surrounded a conference table and waited for the Director to make his appearance. After several minutes, the Director entered the room and placed a chart on the table. "What do you see?" "What do you see?" He demanded. The fellow next to me said, "It says fixed-price incentive." "No, no, look at it," the Director said. It was a chart that depicted a fixed-price incentive (firm target) contract (FPIF). "Look how flat it is," the Director said. I tried to look at the chart but I was more interested in seeing the Director. Out of the corner of my eye, I saw him dressed in a dark suit, vest, watch chain connected to the middle button of his vest and dangling perfectly from one side to the other. He had a paunch and tufts of white hair on his head and he looked like Winston Churchill—the World War II Prime Minister of the United Kingdom. He was Gordon Wade Rule—the highest-ranking civilian in Navy contracting. Years later, I met a colleague of Gordon Rule and told him about my first impressions. The colleague looked at me and laughed, "Gordon not only looked like Churchill, he thought he was Churchill." Since this first meeting with Gordon Rule, I have been interested in the FPIF contract type and how it can be used on government contracts.
The Rule Contract Table 1 is the pricing structure that Gordon Rule was talking about during our meeting. For the purpose of discussion in this article, it will be referred to as the "Rule Contract."
Someone familiar with an FPIF contract will notice what Gordon Rule was talking about. For those who are not, the following discussion explains the mechanics of an FPIF contract pricing structure.
Mechanics of the FPIF Contract
PTA = (Ceiling Price - Target Price)/Government Share + Target Cost All of these points and shares have an effect on costs, profit, and price. However, two tools in the structure—the ceiling price and the share ratio—dramatically affect the potential costs, profits, and prices. For the examples in tables 3, 4, and 5, I use the target cost, target profit, profit rate at target cost, and target price identified in Table 2. The ceiling price and share ratio will vary according to example.
At the ceiling price, the government's liability for cost within the terms of the original contract ends and the contractor pays for all costs above the ceiling price. The setting of the ceiling price significantly affects the relationship between the government and the contractor once the target cost has been reached. The example in Table 3 includes 4 different ceiling prices and the same 70/30 share ratio. Remember, the ceiling price is stated as a percentage of the target cost.
As can be seen, there is no difference in profit for any of the examples where costs are less than the target cost. This is because the ceiling price affects the cost and profit structure somewhere after the target cost is exceeded. Since the ceiling price is used to determine the PTA, it also results in different PTAs. Notice the PTAs for each ceiling price. Prior to the PTA, but after the target cost is reached, the 70/30 share ratio is in effect and the government shares 70 percent of all overruns and the contractor shares 30 percent of all overruns. Once the PTA is reached, the contractor’s profit will be reduced on a dollar-for-dollar basis up to the ceiling price. Remember when Gordon Rule said "Look how flat it is?" He was referring to the incentive curve. The incentive curve reflects the amount of potential profit for each cost level throughout the FPIF structure. The smaller the profit increment as costs increase, the flatter the incentive curve becomes. The flatter the curve becomes, the closer it approaches a cost plus fixed-fee (CPFF) contract since the fixed-fee on a CPFF remains constant for all levels of costs. By increasing the ceiling price on an FPIF contract, the government's share in cost overruns and the contractor's opportunity to recover costs is placed at a higher dollar level. The higher the ceiling price, the flatter the FPIF incentive curve is because it is being stretched in length.
To compare the effect of share ratios on an FPIF structure, Table 4 includes 5 different share ratios ranging from 50/50 to 90/10. As mentioned earlier, the government's share of savings or overruns is the first number in the share ratio. In Table 4, a simple share ratio structure is used—one with the same share ratio throughout the structure— to analyze the effect of different share ratios. Share ratios can be complex and can include more than one share ratio. However, to explain the effects of different share ratios, a simple structure is adequate.
Prior to the target cost, the different share ratios provide profits based on the contractor’s share of saved costs alone. Under the 50/50 share ratio, a contractor can increase its profit by $1 million when costs are $2 million less than the target cost because its share is 50 percent of any savings. On the other hand, with the 90/10 share ratio, a contractor can increase its profit by only $200,000 when costs are $2 million less than the target cost because its share is only 10 percent of any savings. The message is clear—there is less incentive to reduce costs as the government share increases. Ceiling Prices and Share Ratios Working TogetherNow that you have seen the basics for different ceiling prices and different share ratios, it is time to see how they can work together. Table 5 illustrates the effect of different share ratios coupled with different ceiling prices. Compare a 50/50 share ratio with a 115 percent ceiling price structure to that of a 90/10 share ratio with a 135 percent ceiling price structure. Quite a difference!
The 50/50 share ratio and 115 percent ceiling price structure is referred to as a “tight structure” because it places a good deal of cost control incentive on the contractor. On the other hand, the 90/10 share ratio and 135 percent ceiling price structure is referred to as a “loose structure” because there is less cost control incentive placed on the contractor. With the combination of a high ceiling price and a high government share, we have flattened the incentive curve significantly. Now, with what we have seen so far, let's go back to the contract that Gordon Rule was complaining about in 1976. To do this, we will compare a moderate FPIF structure with a 70/30 share ratio and 125 percent ceiling price to the Rule contract.
As Table 6 shows, there is quite a difference between our moderate FPIF structure and the Rule contract. Look at the $95 million dollar cost level. Here the moderate FPIF results in no profit while the Rule Contract provides a 6.32 percent profit rate and a dollar profit of $6 million. This difference is caused by the higher ceiling price and the higher government share of overruns on the Rule Contract. Take a look at the profit rate on costs before the target cost is reached. It increases more slowly on the Rule contract as costs are reduced below the target cost of $76 million. Here, the flattening effect of the higher government share on any cost savings is evident.
For the CPFF contract in Table 7, the fixed-fee is set at the same rate as the target profit on the Rule contract—$9.7 million at a cost of $76 million. Remember that between $64,600,000 and $87,400,000, the share ratio on the Rule contract was 95/5. So, the CPFF share ratio of 100/0 is quite close to that of the Rule contract at 95/5 between $64.6 million and $87.4 million. After $87.4 million, the Rule contract converts to a 90/10 share ratio until the PTA which is between $92 and $93 million. Notice how the percent of fee on costs closely parallels the percent of profit on the Rule contract. As Gordon Rule emphasized, it is flat—it is nearly a CPFF contract. The Federal Acquisition Regulation (FAR) at 16.403-1 (b) explains that an FPIF contract is appropriate when a fair and reasonable incentive and a ceiling can be negotiated that provides the contractor with an appropriate share of the risk and the target profit should reflect this assumption of responsibility. The FAR further points out that an FPIF is to be used only when there is adequate cost or pricing information for establishing reasonable firm targets at the time of initial contract negotiation. Further, FAR 16.401 explains that incentives are designed to motivate contractors to meet government goals and objectives. The guidance in the FAR, although general, appears sound. However, what happens when people and the survival of their programs or their organizations are involved? Unfortunately, the FPIF can be manipulated and abused by government and/or industry. It can be used to submit below anticipated cost offers, to hide huge anticipated overruns, or to deceive the uninitiated who only recognize the phrase "fixed-price."
In the 1970s, 1980s, and into the 1990s, a series of General Accounting Office (GAO) reports discussed cost overruns on shipbuilding contracts. For the most part, these reports discussed FPIF contracts. Table 8 provides a summary of the anticipated cost overruns on most shipbuilding contracts during this period.
As we can see from the table, the majority of the contracts had cost estimates for completion that exceeded the original target costs. Additionally, the amount of estimated cost overruns dwarfed the amount of estimated savings in each GAO report. These numbers defy the law of averages. If we simply look at these results without asking questions, we would declare the FPIF contract type as ineffective. However, there is more to it than that.
How aggressive was the bidding? Here is one example.
Yes, under these two contracts target cost was not the issue. The Navy concluded that the contractors offered to work at a loss somewhere beyond the ceiling price.
If an industry or a contractor is trying to survive in a competitive environment, how might it approach the FPIF. As we have seen, contractors will bid below cost when they believe it is in their interest. Does the FPIF provide an opportunity for a contractor to offer a very low price, expect a very large overrun, and hope for a small profit? Yes, it does. Table 9 provides a theoretical example that includes an FPIF with a 95/5 share ratio and a 135 percent ceiling price. Included in the table is a "proposed target cost" which is the official offer amount that the contractor submits to the government. In the second column, there are a range of the contractor's real goals for its target cost.
Assume that the contractor sets a goal of a 4 percent profit on costs. From past experience, the contractor expects that the government will be willing to negotiate a 95/5 share ratio, a 135 percent ceiling price, and a 10 percent profit rate at target cost. The contractor proposes a target cost of $100,000,000 but is really focusing on the 4 percent profit amount. At that profit rate, the contractor's actual target cost goal is $129,807,000. The government determines that the offer is fair and reasonable and negotiations are completed. At the time of agreement on the pricing structure, $100,000,000 is the contractual target cost and the contractor's actual goal is $129,807,000 for a target cost. In effect, the contract is negotiated with nearly a 30 percent cost overrun and a 4 percent profit.
Does a government organization ever have an interest in understating the cost of an item? The President's Blue Ribbon Commission on Defense Procurement, popularly known as the Packard Commission, gave us the following answer.
If the government has an interest in underestimating the cost of a system, it can use an FPIF to its advantage by simply loosening the pricing structure of the FPIF contract. Let's look at an actual example—the original contract for the Trident submarine awarded in 1974.
As can be seen, the contract had a 95/5 share ratio and an incredible ceiling price of 152 percent of target cost. Here is what Gordon Rule had to say about this pricing structure
Once a system receives budget approval with an understated cost, the government must find a way to contract for it at that underestimated cost. The FPIF provides the opportunity in two ways. First, it allows the government to hide expected overruns at the time the contract is awarded. Or, in Gordon Rule's words, it allows the government to include "an obvious overrun of target cost built in." 6 Second, the term "fixed-price" can be used to disguise a cost-reimbursement contract. For example, in regard to the Trident contract, the Commander of the Naval Ship Systems Command, explained 7
Some Final Thoughts Does the FPIF contract have a place in federal contracting? I think it does when it is used as it is intended. However, it can and has been abused. In testing an FPIF structure, there are a number of things I ask. Here are several.
If I do identify a suspicious FPIF structure, I turn to the facts surrounding the negotiation of the target cost. For example,
1 Navy Contracting: Cost Overruns and Claims Potential on Navy Shipbuilding Contracts, GAO/NSIAD-88-15, October 16, 1987, p. 9 |
Copyright © 2023 by Robert Antonio
1 Comment
Recommended Comments